280
k. d. m. snell
data,67 and is certainly true for these English parishes.68 It can also be
demonstrated for other and earlier English data.69 Additional factors
positively associated with endogamy were the population growth rate
(1811-41), average numbers of marriages per annum, the proportions of
families engaged in trade (1831), measures of religious denominational
diversity (calculated from the 1851 religious census),70 the value of
67 Flandrin, Families in former times, pp. 34-5, 47. This cites late seventeenth- and eighteenth-
century figures from villages in the Vallage suggesting that the larger the village, the higher the
degree of endogamy. In very small villages, the percentages could be as low as 31 to 34. In others
they rose to over 70%, up to 93% in one case, sometimes associated with violence against outsiders
trying to court village women (which was also often documented for England and Wales). In some
mountain villages (e.g. Caillac) topographical conditions could compound this and induce very high
figures indeed. Such ‘startlingly high’ figures led to very dense kinship ties. It might be expected
that the English rural changes towards higher endogamy would also intensify village kin ties and
produce high surname densities (which certainly obtained in some Norfolk parishes). This would
have many implications for community formation and consciousness. Furthermore, while the caveats
made above regarding links between ‘place of origin’, migration, and residency upon marriage should
not be forgotten, it is worth pointing out that high kinship densities could well conduce to lower
marriage ages. As King has suggested, they ‘would tend towards lower female marriage ages through
more, and more certain, courtship opportunities’. King, ‘English historical demography’, p. 150.
Such densities would have enhanced the roles of relatives and ‘friends’, facilitating contacts based
on trust and knowledge, providing more local support for young couples, and so on. (I use the
term ‘friends’ in the sense of the English labouring poor: to denote both ‘family’ and closely linked
people, whether they be kin or those in close upbrought or dependent alliance.)
68 This finding could be extended to remark on another area of debate. It is an interesting
historical paradox that the most ‘closed’ or ‘estate’ parishes had to bring in many outsiders to marry
(by virtue of their deliberately ‘closed’ nature and small populations), while the more ‘open’ or
populous parishes could rely more upon their own populations to obtain marital partners. Such an
effect was contrary to some of the dispositions towards closure that brought ‘closed’ parishes into
being. Labour shortages in ‘closed’ parishes may also have conduced to similar ends, and temporary
in-coming labour was one way in which potential marriage partners resident elsewhere might be
met. Of my 69 parishes, Kedleston, Helhoughton, Hanborough, and Langton Herring had property
held ‘in one hand’, and Breadsall, Elvaston, East Stower, Rampisham, Swyre, Downham, Birstall,
Eastwell, Queniborough, East Barsham, North Barsham, Holme-by-the-Sea, Toftrees, Bothal,
Edlingham, Ingram, Longhoughton, Pyrton, and Cocking had property held ‘in a few hands’. I use
here the landownership classifications of Wilson, ed., Imperial gazetteer, which are favourably assessed
as evidence in Snell and Ell, Rival Jerusalems, app. E, pp. 440-8. This distribution of the 69 parishes
into categories of landownership, as judged from this source, is exactly representative of broader
patterns for the most ‘closed’ parishes (5.8%), and shows fewer parishes than expected being ‘in a
few hands’ (28%, as compared with an expected 54%). See ibid., tab. 7.2, p. 225.
69 Mitson, ‘Significance of kinship networks’, pp. 60, 74; Phythian-Adams, Re-thinking English local
history, p. 35; O’Hara, Courtship and constraint, pp. 123, 132-3, 135-7. I have re-analysed Mitson’s
figures for 11 parishes (1561-1710) along the lines of my presentation, using an unweighted mean
of her population totals from five sources (1603-1743). They show much the same positive relation-
ship (Pearson’s r = 0.599) between population size and parochial endogamy as do my parishes.
Curiously, their positive scatter is parallel to, but noticeably below, a linear trend for my (later)
data, suggesting significantly lower endogamy (about 20% lower) for any given population size in
1561-1710 compared with 1700-1837. (Any poorer registration earlier would produce the loss of
some information about differential residency, and so would predispose to seemingly higher endogamy
at earlier dates.) If this is a valid evidential and historical finding, it has very interesting implications
indeed for the structure of communities and kinship densities over time, and it may suggest a
longer-term rise in endogamy commencing well before 1700. It is also necessary to consider the
possibility of even earlier cycles, and I have in mind the downward shift in endogamous courtships
documented by O’Hara for Kentish parishes (1475-1594), in her Courtship and constraint, pp. 127-
9. As with Mitson, however, O’Hara’s mean figure of 47% of courtship cases being co-resident
parochially (if translated into ‘endogamous marriages’) is well below the later figures from my work.
This throws into sharp relief the very high parochial endogamy of the period c. 1780-1840.
70 For further discussion of such measures, see Snell and Ell, Rival Jerusalems, app. C,
esp. pp. 436-7.
Economic History Society 2002