426
M.G. Colombo, M. Delmastro / Economics Letters 69 (2000) 421–427
In regressions III and IV a further distinction is made between State-owned plants, plants that
belong to Italian private groups, and plants owned by foreign multinational enterprises. Failure rates
of plants in both the Italian private group and foreign multinational categories turn out to be
substantially larger than in the independent plant category, with the coefficients of such variables
being positive and significant at 99% and 90% respectively. In addition, likelihood of survival would
seem to be larger and less sensitive to plant size for foreign owned units than for establishments of
Italian groups; in particular, in regression IV the coefficient of SIZE for foreign owned plants is not
significant, while it is significant at 95% (and negative) for nationally owned ones (see the value of the
Wald tests in Table 3). As the decision by a foreign multinational enterprise to close a plant often
1
implies abandoning the country, the lower failure rate of foreign owned units may be justified by the
larger exit and re-entry sunk costs involved by plant closure. Instead, the exit behavior of Italian
State-owned enterprises seems to diverge from that of their private counterparts. The coefficient of
STATEOWNED in regression III is statistically not significant at conventional levels (even though it
is positive). This may be regarded as a consequence of the peculiar social objectives pursued by
State-owned enterprises; it may also signal the social and political pressures to which such firms are
exposed, leading to higher exit costs. The estimates of regression IV also suggest that such reasoning
especially applies to large sized State-owned units. Note in fact the large magnitude of the (negative)
coefficient of the plant size variable significant at 90% (see again the Wald test in Table 3).
Acknowledgements
Financial support from University of Pavia 1997 FAR funds is gratefully acknowledged. We wish to
thank participants in the 1998 EEA Conference, Berlin. The authors are jointly responsible for the
work. However, Sections 1 and 2 have been written by Massimo G. Colombo, Section 3 by Marco
Delmastro.
References
Audretsch, D., Mahmood, T., 1995. New firm survival: New results using a hazard function. Review of Economics and
Statistics 77, 97–103.
Baden-Fuller, C., 1989. Exit from declining industries and the case of steel castings. Economic Journal 99, 949–961.
Colombo, M.G., Delmastro, M., 1999. Technology use and plant closure, Research Policy, forthcoming.
Dixit, A., Pindyck, R., 1994. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Dunne, T., Roberts, M.J., Samuelson, L., 1988. Pattern of firm entry and exit in US manufacturing industries. RAND Journal
of Economics 19, 495–515.
Dunne, T., Roberts, M.J., Samuelson, L., 1989. The growth and failure of US manufacturing plants. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 104, 671–698.
Ghemawat, P., Nalebuff, B., 1990. The devolution of declining industries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, 167–186.
Lieberman, M.B., 1990. Exit from declining industries: shakeout or stakeout. RAND Journal of Economics 21, 538–553.
1According to information provided by the REPRINT database, which monitors foreign direct investments in Italy on a
regular basis since 1983, out of 1279 foreign multinationals, which were present in Italy in the manufacturing industry at the
end of 1989, 1032 (that is, 80.7%) operated a single plant.