Making the IMF and the World Bank more accountable
way in which the numbers of programme ‘objectives’ being included in loans
and programmes have increased, with countries now being required to under-
take actions such as to mobilize, redefine, strengthen or upgrade government
processes in an ever wider range of areas.
The new conditionality is dramatically deepening and broadening the pur-
view of the international financial institutions within member countries. No
longer are they engaged in monitoring specific macroeconomic policy targets in
the context of a crisis, or specific project loans and conditions. Both institutions
are now engaging governments in negotiations which cover virtually all issues
in economic policy-making—and beyond, with ‘good governance’ extending
into areas such as the rule of law, judicial reform, corporate governance and so
forth. This new, wide-ranging domain of advice and conditionality directly
affects a broader swathe of policies, people, groups and organizations within
countries.
Yet the IMF and the World Bank were neither created nor structured to
undertake or to be accountable for such far-reaching activities. They were
created to deal with a narrow, clearly stipulated range of technical issues. For
this reason, at their birth it was decided that they should deal with member
countries only through the treasury, finance ministry, central bank or like
institution of a country, and that only representatives of such agencies could sit
on the Boards of the institutions.12 This is still true today.
Meanwhile, the work of both the IMF and the World Bank has broadened
and deepened far beyond the purviews of the finance ministries or central banks
with which they are negotiating. This means that, through conditionality and
loan agreements, the Fund and Bank are making finance ministries or central
banks formally accountable for policies which should properly lie within the
scope of other agencies, and for which those other agencies are domestically
accountable. A policy affecting the distribution of health care, for example, we
would expect to be the responsibility of a minister of health, whom we would
expect to be answerable for it to voters and his or her society at large. Yet as the
Fund and Bank intrude further into these kinds of decisions, the risk is that the
line of accountability they establish with the Finance Ministry or Central Bank
will override other agencies and local or democratic accountability.13
A further implication is that, while in theory different agencies within govern-
ment compete for and debate competing priorities and goals, negotiations with
the Fund and Bank distort these debates, subjecting broad areas of policy to the
narrower focus, priorities and analysis of the central bank and finance ministry—
even though neither necessarily has the desire, mandate, accountability or
expertise to evaluate and formulate policy in respect of these broader issues. In a
subtle way, this point is underscored by a remark in the external evaluation of
1
2
3
World Bank Articles of Agreement, Article III, 6.2; IMF Articles of Agreement, Article V, section 1.
Of course, the external line of accountability does not always produce the outcomes desired by the IFIs,
as argued by Paul Collier, ‘Learning from failure: the international financial institutions as agencies of
restraint in Africa’, in Schedler et al., The self-restraining state, pp. 313–32.
1
89