1
5. A secondary problem is that it is
he gave it up as hopeless (personal com-
munication to author).
ally never correct (e.g., PDFs are simply
not constant).
very difficult even to define a set of set-
tlement rules that make sense here. The
difficulty of defining a sensible settle-
ment process is creating difficulties for
the efforts to develop a workable hybrid
at MISO and perhaps elsewhere, but is
not discussed here.
24. F.C. Schweppe, M.C. Caramanis,
28. Actually, this is true only if an FTR is
a one-way option, so that an A-to-B FTR
and a B-to-A FTR are different. With
N nodes, there are Nϫ(N–1)/2 differ-
ent point-to-point pairs if A-to-B is
the same as B-to-A. Thus, with 100
nodes there could be “only” 4,950 bi-
directional FTRs.
R.D. Tabors, and R.E. Bohn, Spot Pric-
ing of Electricity (Norwell, MA: Klu-
wer, 1988).
25. William W. Hogan, E. Grant Read,
and Brendan J. Ring, Using Mathematical
Programming for Electricity Spot Pricing,
in Energy Models for Policy and
Planning, International Transactions of
Operational Research, Vol. 3, No. 3/4,
16. In this simple case, redispatch would
require paying some scheduled/hedged
generation in GEN not to run and pay-
ing some unscheduled/unhedged gen-
eration at LOAD to run out-of-merit.
29. If a portfolio of n FGRs can include
any of N Ͼ n different FGRs, there can be
N!/[n!ϫ(N Ϫ n)!] qualitatively different
portfolios. If N ϭ 50 and n ϭ 10, the
resulting number is 10,272,278,170.
1996.
17. Supra note 2, at 44–46. As discussed
below, Chao and Peck suggest a different
nonsolution to the problem of too many
FGRs in a footnote within their article.
30. Under a use-it-or-lose-it rule, any-
body holding an inventory of FGRs must
find a buyer for all of its FGRs or be left
with nothing of value in real time. But
buyers could always wait to buy trans-
mission in the spot market by paying
real-time congestion charges. It is hard to
imagine how anybody could afford to
make a market in such FGRs. An FGR
bazaar might be more plausible without
a use-it-or-lose-it rule, but even so a
small market maker would be at a tre-
mendous disadvantage. It seems inevita-
ble that FGR trading would become a
centralized, monopoly activity.
1
8. Supra note 2, at note 18. As discussed
above, Chao and Peck suggest a different
nonsolution in the text of their article.
19. There is no FGR portfolio that per-
fectly hedges congestion on flowgate A
in every contingency for all transactions,
because different PDFs will apply to
each different point-to-point transaction.
For the same reason, there is no FGR
portfolio that perfectly hedges conges-
tion on all flowgates in contingency X for
all transactions. In principle it is possible
to create an FGR portfolio that perfectly
hedges against congestion on all flow-
gates in all contingencies for a specified
point-to-point transaction. These are
called FTRs.
31. Supra note 8.
3
2. See PJM Market News, Vol. 1, No. 1,
2
6. A dispatch or set of FTRs is said to be
Oct. 2000, for information on the vol-
ume of energy and FTRs traded in PJM
markets.
simultaneously feasible if it satisfies all
of the actual and contingent constraints
used for dispatch. To be explicit about
what should be obvious but is some-
times confusing, a simultaneously feasi-
ble dispatch does not have to be feasible
even if all contingencies were to occur
simultaneously. No dispatch could meet
these conditions.
20. William Hogan, Flowgate Rights and
Wrongs, working paper, John F. Kennedy
School of Government, Harvard Univer-
sity, Aug. 20, 2000, at 20.
33. If something is valuable to its current
owners one would not expect it to be
offered for sale unless the prospective
buyers are willing to offer high prices for
it. And if the current owners fear that
they will not be allowed to keep any
trading profits but will be stuck with any
trading losses—a dilemma commonly
created by regulation—they will be
reluctant to sell even when they
21. Andrew L. Ott, Can Flowgates Really
Work? An Analysis of Transmission Con-
gestion in the PJM Market from April 1,
1998–April 30, 2000, PJM Interconnec-
tion, Sept. 15, 2000.
27. Given the nonconvex nature of elec-
tricity systems—economies of scale,
integer choices, etc.—such sweeping
assertions require some technical quali-
fications, and it is possible to create
counterexamples using unrealistic
numerical examples. But the important
assumptions of LMP/FTR theory
appear to be valid over wide ranges of
actual conditions on real systems, in
sharp contrast to the assumptions of
flowgate/FGR theory, which are virtu-
22. Supra note 3.
23. William W. Hogan, Contract Networks
“should” according to normal commer-
for Electric Power Transmission, 4 J. Reg.
Econ., 1992, at 211–42. Grant Read of
Canterbury University in New Zealand
was an early collaborator with Hogan.
Read spent some time in the late 1980s
and early 1990s developing a link-based
approach to transmission pricing and
congestion management, but says that
cial and economic criteria.
34. For example, the regional reliability
process may decide that the RTO should
replace an N–1 standard with an N–2
standard on some elements. This would
reduce the usable capacity of the grid
just as a grid outage would.
January/February 2001
© 2001, Elsevier Science Inc., 1040-6190/01/$–see front matter PII S1040-6190(00)00174-3 55