Young and Westcott
How Decoupled is U.S. Agricultural Support
763
countries to take into account the effects of
their domestic policies on the international
marketplace. The WTO is not concernedwith
the rationale or justification for different pro-
grams, but with the impact of the programs
on trade.
Production Flexibility Contract Payments
The 1996 U.S. Farm Act fundamentally
changedagriculture income support pro-
grams by replacing the target price/deficiency
payment program with a new program of
production flexibility contract (PFC) pay-
ments that are generally not relatedto cur-
rent farm-level production or market prices.
Total outlays for the payments were capped
at slightly over $36 billion for seven years,
1996–2002. To be eligible to receive payments,
farmers enteredinto proudction flexibility
contracts, requiring compliance with conser-
vation, wetland, and planting flexibility pro-
visions, as well as keeping the landin agri-
cultural uses (which includes idling). Land
eligible for PFCs included acreage enrolled
in annual farm programs for any year from
1991 through 1995. Payments under these
contracts are basedon enrolledacreage and
generally are not relatedto current plantings.
In its WTO notifications, the UnitedStates
reports PFC payments as decoupled green
box payments. Whether or not these pay-
ments are totally decoupled has been ques-
tioned(Tielu andRoberts, Hennessy). These
authors argue that PFC payments are at least
partially coupledsince they increase farm
operator wealth, which has several potential
effects on production. First, lenders are more
willing to make loans to farmers with higher
guaranteedincomes because of a lower risk
of default. This increase in loan availabil-
ity may facilitate additional agricultural pro-
duction. Second, with increased income from
PFC payments, farmers can more easily
invest in their farm operation. For example,
increased income may facilitate additional
agricultural investments by farmers who are
constrainedby debt or limitedliquidity. The
resulting increasedinvestment in farm oper-
ations contributes to higher agricultural pro-
duction in the long run. Another potential
effect of PFC payments on production is that
a guaranteedincome stream may make farm-
ers more willing to undertake riskier crops or
strategies which have the possibility of higher
returns. An increase in wealth resulting from
PFC payments can change farmers’ views of
the penalties associatedwith risk levels of
wealth changes. Farmers’ responses to risk,
therefore, might be very different at higher
levels of wealth. Such a change in risk atti-
tude can affect the mix of crops produced.
Initially, a decoupled payment affects farm-
ers in the same way as a lump sum payment.
Some farm programs mostly influence
aggregate landuse, with less effect on the
mix of crops planted. Commodity nonspe-
cific transfers, for example, can increase
the overall level of agricultural production
by increasing the wealth of farmers and
thereby increasing agricultural investments.
This increase in wealth shifts out the pro-
duction possibilities frontier for all produc-
tion, raising use of landandother inputs.
Greater wealth does not affect the rela-
tive marginal returns from producing alterna-
tive crops, allowing market signals in general
to allocate the additional acreage. Penalties
associatedwith risk may be perceiveddiffer-
ently by people who have different levels of
wealth and, therefore, farmers’ responses to
risk may vary with their wealth levels.
Other programs are linkedmore closely
to production of specific crops and thus dis-
tort the mix of crops planted in addition to
total landuse. Direct coupling occurs when
program benefits are linkedto the produc-
tion of specific crops, so that those bene-
fits increase the expectedmarginal returns
to the commodity. Production decisions are
basedon the level of government payments
in addition to expected returns from the mar-
ketplace. Cross-commodity effects can also
result, because changes in expectedreturns
for one commodity affect relative net returns
as well, thereby influencing decisions to pro-
duce other crops. For farmers with land con-
straints, a coupledsubsidy wouldlikely alter
the mix of crops planted, switching toward
the subsidized (or more highly subsidized)
crops. However, since some farmers wouldbe
able to expandlanduse, aggregate acreage
couldincrease with the mix of crops shifting
towardthose with higher relative subsidies.
In addition to the effects of current pay-
ments, agricultural production can also be
affectedby programs that influence expecta-
tions. Programs that reduce risk, for example,
modify the lower end of the distribution of
expectedreturns andcan leadto production
distortions (Hennessy). Expectations about
the nature of future programs may also affect
current production decisions. For example, if
farmers expect future payments to be based
on current plantings, they may keep current
plantings of those crops high.