TRADING RECOMMENDATIONS
93
the mean earnings of all firms. They conclude this relation is due, in part,
to unanticipated earnings shocks. Unexpected positive (negative) earnings
shocks result in higher (lower) unanticipated earnings and will generally
be associated with more negative (positive) forecast errors. More formally,
suppose that reported scaled earnings at time t for firm i, Eit, can be decom-
posed into a predictable component, EPit, and an unpredictable component
or earnings shock, eUit ∼ N(0, σ). Then Eit = EPit + eUit. We can model the
analysts’ scaled forecasts, Fit, of Eit as a function of the predictable com-
ponent: Fit = EPit + fit, where a non-zero mean value for the error term,
fit, is consistent with forecast bias (either intentional or unintentional). We
define forecast error as: FEit = Fit − Eit = (EPit + fit) − (EPit + eUit), or FEit =
fit − eUit. Thus, assuming no forecast bias, unpredictable earnings shocks will
result in an inverse relation between forecast error and reported earnings.6
To plot the relationship between scaled forecast error and scaled earnings
we divide our sample of 35,482 observations (including the 870 observations
with unavailable recommendations) into 20 equally-sized portfolios based
on the magnitude of scaled earnings. Figure 1 illustrates portfolio mean and
median scaled forecast errors plotted by portfolio median scaled earnings.
The inverse relationship depicted in figure 1 is consistent with results in
Eames, Glover, and Stice [2001] that, on average, firms experiencing large
positive (negative) earnings shocks are more likely to have positive (nega-
7
tive) earnings and negative (positive) forecast errors. Regressing scaled
analyst forecast errors on scaled actual earnings results in an R-squared of
48 percent and a negative slope significant at the .001 level (table 2, panel B).
If earnings are also associated with analyst recommendations, earn-
ings could be an important correlated omitted variable in prior studies
examining the relationship between forecast errors and recommendations.
Figure 2 plots mean and median scaled earnings by recommendation and
6
Because earnings is included on both the right and left-hand side of the equation, i.e.,
FE = F − E = B0 + B1E + e , there may be concern that this linear model will force an
it
it
it
it
it
algebraic inverse association between FEit and Eit. However, an algebraic association between
forecast error and earnings does not necessitate an observed inverse association. Fit is a function
of Eit,thus we do not necessarily expect a negative value for B1, and only obtain a negative value
under restrictive assumptions regarding the behavior of Fit with respect to Eit. To see this, we
∂
∂
F
differentiate both sides of the preceding equation with respect to Eit, obtain
− 1 = B1, and
E
∂
F
∂F
∂E
note that B1 is negative only if
either of these conditions a priori. For our sample
< 1, and B1 = −1 only if
= 0. There is no basis for asserting
∂
E
∂
∂
F
E
= .48 and is significantly different from
zero at the 1% level. Thus, the inverse association between forecast error and earnings is
not algebraic. Rather, a systematic inverse relationship between forecast errors and earnings
requires systematic analyst behavior. For example, the inability of analysts to forecast some
component or portion of earnings. Because we focus on scaled earnings, we assume that the
scaled earnings shock has constant variance across firms.
7
The optimistic forecast errors associated with lower earnings are consistent with the man-
agement relations hypothesis given that sell recommendations are commonly associated with
low earnings. Although the management relations hypothesis could be contributing to the ob-
served relation between forecast error and earnings, it cannot explain the pessimism observed
at higher earnings observations because the management relations hypothesis predicts only
optimism.