1244
The Journal of Finance
Large movements of equity prices are often associated with the changes in
fundamental economic variables such as interest rates, corporate earnings,
and dividends. Therefore, to a large extent, Pástor and Stambaugh’s prior
distribution captures the changes in the equity premium, especially the drop
of equity premium in the late 1990s, in a rather reasonable way. However, it
might be more fruitful to incorporate valuation models into the prior distri-
bution rather than the simple accounting rule. Such a prior distribution will
combine the information obtained from the interest rates and price-earnings
ratios. Given the large quantity of literature on the valuation of the aggre-
gate equity market based on fundamental economic variables, it is natural
that these variables affect economists’ prior beliefs in the equity premium.
C. The Range of Shifts in the Equity Premium
Pástor and Stambaugh believe that large shifts in the equity premium are
unlikely. To express such a belief, the prior distribution of the equity pre-
miums in stable regimes, denoted by the vector m, is specified as
1
2sm2
p~m6mT ! @ exp Ϫ
~m Ϫ mT i!'~m Ϫ mT i! , m Ͼ 0
~4!
ͫ
ͬ
where mT is a positive hyperparameter following a noninformative prior dis-
tribution, and i is the vector of 1s. Pástor and Stambaugh use the variance
sm2 to control the strength of the belief. As expected, the main effect of this
prior belief is to dampen the fluctuations of the estimated equity premium
over regimes. Comparing the solid curves in Figure 2 and Figure 4 of Pástor
and Stambaugh’s paper, the plots of the estimated equity premium are very
similar, except that the one in Figure 2 has a much narrower range than the
one in Figure 4. Without the prior belief expressed by equation ~4!, the es-
timated equity premium ranges from 4 to 10 percent rather than from 4 to
6 percent. Clearly, the prior belief expressed by equation ~4! is needed to
shrink the estimate to the desired range.
All of us should wonder why large shifts in the equity premium are un-
likely. Although Pástor and Stambaugh pose this belief as a wise man’s wis-
dom, it is useful for us to think of some economic reasons. If the equity
premium is the premium on risk, it will have large shifts either because
equity risk jumps or because investors’ risk aversion changes drastically.
Since the volatility of the U.S. equity index fluctuates within some range,
the link between the premium and the volatility should constrain the shifts
in the equity premium. The degree of risk aversion is usually implied in the
valuation model. Therefore, the prior belief in the link between the premium
and volatility and the prior belief in the valuation model should already
impose restrictions on the shifts in the equity premium. If the prior beliefs
in the two economic models work well, we should not need the informative
prior distribution expressed by equation ~4!.